Bank Automation News

No products in the cart.

Subscribe
  • News
  • Data
  • Transactions
  • Events
    • Bank Automation Summit
    • Apply to Speak
    • Apply to Demo
  • Podcast
  • WEBINARS
    • On-Demand Webinar: Emerging fintechs: New technologies you need to know now
    • Webinar Library
Log In
No Result
View All Result
  • AI
  • Business Banking
  • Core
  • Cloud
  • Payments
  • Retail Banking
  • Risk & Security
Bank Automation News
  • News
  • Data
  • Transactions
  • Events
    • Bank Automation Summit
    • Apply to Speak
    • Apply to Demo
  • Podcast
  • WEBINARS
    • On-Demand Webinar: Emerging fintechs: New technologies you need to know now
    • Webinar Library
BAN PLUS
Log In
No Result
View All Result
Bank Automation News
No Result
View All Result

No Economic Recovery Until Banking System Crisis Resolved

Gregg KillorenbyGregg Killoren
March 3, 2009
in Archive
Reading Time: 9 mins read
0
Share on Facebook

For the better part of a year now, this author has documented his opinion and those of many notable economists that a resolution of the credit crisis, resulting in the normalization of lending activity and pricing, was necessary before any economic recovery could be possible (more at Raw Finance blog).

That is not to say that returning the financial industry to a more normal state of operations is the only criteria for an economic recovery; certainly the public sector needs to fill the spending vacuum left by the private sector in the interim. That is what the fiscal stimulus package, officially titled the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act, is designed to do. However, the effect of the stimulus will be severely muted if the banking industry remains frozen.

Numerous solutions to the credit problem have been posited by various sources. However, as Salvatore Rossi, Managing Director for Research, Economics, and International Relations at the Bank of Italy writes, the solutions may be broadly categorized into two schools of thought:

Government purchase of banks’ distressed assets; and
Government recapitalization of banks’ balance sheets.

It is interesting to note that the Troubled Asset Relief Program, now known as the Financial Stability Plan, began with the first school of thought as its goal, and later morphed into a watered-down, disorganized version of the second school of thought. Former Treasury Secretary Henry M. Paulson, Jr., found it too difficult to price the distressed assets.

As noted in prior posts on this blog, pricing of the assets would result in overpayment in some instances, providing a windfall to certain banks, and underpayment in others, causing some banks to fail on the spot. This would happen because there is no market for the so-called “toxic” assets, and so, each bank has applied its own formula to pricing the assets for purposes of reporting its balance sheet condition, resulting in a wide range of prices for the same assets. Paulson then embarked on a piecemeal recapitalization of banks by generally purchasing preferred shares of stock. While TARP should be commended for averting an all-out collapse of the financial system, credit spreads are still too high, demonstrating a continued unease in the system, resulting in little lending activity and expensive loans for borrowers who gain access. Put simply, the program did not go far enough. And now, the new administration has enacted a fiscal stimulus bill before taking measures to get credit flowing again. The government needs to get its priorities straight.

Moreover, the success of the President’s budget may hang in the balance. Without repairing the financial system, President Obama’s forecast of economic growth, vital to his budget proposal, may not come to fruition. In fact, it conflicts with other experts’ analysis. Greg Mankiw, Professor of Economics at Harvard University, writes on his blog:

“Here (in red) are the growth forecasts used to put out the new Obama administration budget, followed by the consensus forecast of a panel of “Blue Chip” private forecasters (in blue, naturally). (Source. Go to Table 3.)

2009: -1.2% -1.9%
2010: +3.2% +2.1%
2011: +4.0% +2.9%
2012: +4.6% +2.9%
2013: +4.2% +2.8%

Accumulating the difference, you find that Team Obama projects about 6 percent higher GDP in 2013 than do private forecasters.”

As Salvatore Rossi writes, the best plan likely involves both approaches. Extraordinary times require extraordinary acts, but timing is also an issue. The longer the government waits to act on banks, the worse the situation becomes for the entire economy. One need only look at today’s announced revision of fourth-quarter 2008 gross domestic product to -6.2 percent to know that the window of opportunity to avert a major economic crisis is shrinking.

Rossi’s article, originally published at VOXeu.org is republished below:

To come out of it, use all the exits and get the incentives right
Salvatore Rossi
VOXeu.org
25 February 2009

“There are two schools of thought on how to get credit flowing again. One suggests buying the toxic assets, the other says to recapitalise banks. This column says that both approaches are necessary, though the right balance will vary across nations. The real difficulty is aligning incentives – in both pricing assets and recapitalising banks, bank managers’ interests may thwart governments’ objectives.

Let’s recapitulate some basic facts and analyses. A recession/depression spiral is gathering strength all over the world. To stop it, we need first to get credit to flow again. This is an absolute precondition. No fiscal package, however big and well conceived, can work unless the heart attack that has stricken the global financial system is cured first. On this, there is a vast consensus of opinion.
Consensus on the problem
Credit is rarefied because several banks have a structural balance sheet imbalance. In the last five to ten years, banks across the globe, to varying degrees, borrowed too much relative to their capital and used too much of these borrowed resources to buy assets that proved to be toxic. Now such banks must deleverage. But the uncertainty surrounding the “true” value of their assets is keeping private investors from holding those banks’ shares, lending them money, or purchasing their assets. So the only way they can deleverage is to cut lending to the economy. This worsens the recession, which in turn increases the “bad” portion of banks’ assets, in a downward spiral.

Clearly, this is a market failure, and the public sector must step in. How? Here opinions have not yet converged.

Divergence on the solutions: Two schools of thought

There are two basic schools of thought.

One says that government should intervene on the banks’ asset side by buying distressed assets.
The other counters that government should rather intervene on the liability side, recapitalising the banks.
The former poses one tremendous problem – how to price assets for which a market no longer exists. The latter poses a problem of governance (moral hazard) that is no less serious.

In the US last year, TARP I was to take the first route, setting toxic asset prices through reverse auctions. This soon proved technically unfeasible, so the program was re-oriented towards the other aim, i.e. recapitalising banks (TARP II). To some extent ($240 billion) that was done, through preferred shares so the control/management of the banks was not called into question. This occasionally sparked public outrage, as people saw a lot of taxpayers’ money flowing into the pockets of banks’ shareholders and managers without any apparent success in unblocking the credit market or halting the recession.

Caballero’s Knightian uncertainty and solution: Universal public insurance
Ricardo Caballero has argued on this site that the uncertainty ravaging credit and financial markets is Knightian, i.e. not amenable to probabilistic assessment. In these circumstances, each individual reacts to the worst-case scenario, which is in general different for the two sides of any transaction, thus leading to an extremely risk-averse behaviour and to a very inefficient double (or multiple) counting and hoarding of resources (liquidity). Hence the main (though not exclusive) role of government should be to provide explicit and systemic insurance, at non-Knightian (pre-crisis) prices.

In this analysis, while the amount of capital required to restore normal conditions would be very large, to offset the inefficient hoarding of resources, the impact of the provision of insurance, by removing for each agent the worst-case scenario, would be multiplied several times over. Essentially, Caballero calls for a variation of the asset-side approach – a universal public insurance for distressed bank assets, at (or slightly below) pre-crisis values, offered to every market participant.

Sachs’ idea on toxic asset pricing
Jeffrey Sachs has suggested solving the dilemma of pricing toxic assets by building a bridge linking the two basic approaches. He wants the public sector to buy distressed assets at face value (swapping them for government bonds for long enough for the storm to blow over), thus effectively cleaning up banks’ balance sheets.

What about moral hazard? Sachs’s idea is that the government should receive warrants on each bank’s capital, contingent on the eventual sale price of the swapped assets. Once the economy is back on track and the assets are liquid again (say, a year from now), if the assets’ value is at least equal to today’s capital, the latter will absorb the possible loss and taxpayers will be safe. If not, taxpayers will sustain the residual loss and the bank will be then nationalised (for resale to private investors as soon as market conditions permit). Since the asset liquidation process is necessarily gradual, in the interim the government should have a sort of receivership, in order to make sure managers cannot strip off good assets.

Geithner’s Plan
Timothy Geithner’s Financial Stability Plan for the US combines the two approaches. In part, it returns to the original TARP intention of cleaning up the asset side of balance sheets, but in a new way. The government will ask willing private investors (private equity or hedge funds?) to find a price for the distressed assets of a bank and to go halves with the public sector in buying them (the details have not been fully disclosed). The Plan also provides finance to private investors willing to purchase new securitised bank loans to small businesses and consumers. On top of that, a capital provisioning scheme is envisaged, whereby government can buy convertible preferred shares (“contingent equity”) issued by capital-short banks, with some conditionality concerning such matters as dividends and acquisitions. The precondition is that these banks must have undergone a comprehensive “stress test” to ascertain all potential losses, due both to toxic “legacy” assets and to the economic downswing.

Other countries have adopted or are considering measures classed in the two categories set forth above:
buying distressed assets (through a “special vehicle,” a “bad bank” or whatever) or providing insurance on them; recapitalising banks.
I’d like to make two general points.

Two general points
First of all, it seems to me that in the countries most affected by the phenomenon of distressed assets in banks’ balance sheets, the two approaches are both necessary at the present juncture, although of course the right mix between them will vary with national specificities.
The main merit of Mr. Geithner’s Plan is precisely that it pursues both. Relying only on the first would mean dangerous underestimation of insolvency risks (see Martin Wolf’s severe critique on “why Obamas’s new TARP will fail to rescue the banks”). Relying only on recapitalisation is subject to Caballero’s objection based on the peculiar state of uncertainty characterising the present crisis, which has blurred the boundary between illiquidity and insolvency. In countries where the “legacy” of past sins in banks’ assets is heavy, it may be preferable to complement recapitalisation with some form of asset cleaning, better if in the form suggested by Jeffrey Sachs.

But the devil is always in the (missing) details, and this is my second point.

What determines the success or failure of any measure is the following question: “Are the incentives of all players right or wrong?”
In this connection, more than shareholders, the people to watch carefully are the managers of the banks.

It remains a general principle that a private agent is more suitable than a state bureaucrat for managing an enterprise efficiently. After the miserable show recently put on by so many bankers in some countries, some people there will find this hard to believe. But we must not mistake conflicts of interest and agency problems for lack of professional expertise.

Getting the bankers to help
Let’s make two assumptions. First, that government agrees on this general principle (which is certainly the case in America and Britain, perhaps less in continental Europe) and wants to use the technical expertise of today’s bank managers as much and as long as possible, though putting limits to their “greed”. There is clearly a problem of incentive compatibility here. Why? Because managers – and that’s the second assumption – are better informed than anyone else (shareholders and government in particular) on the true value of their assets (i.e. their likely post-crisis value). It may well be that at the onset of the crisis many bank managers had lost control over the content and valuation of most structured assets, but it’s reasonable to assume that by now they are well aware of what is in their portfolios and able to attach a shadow price to each illiquid asset.
Under these assumptions government’s support may be hindered by adverse managers’ incentives. Here are a few examples.

The government’s interest is to induce banks’ managers to reveal the exact amount of distressed assets in the balance sheet of their bank. But:

If the government offers to buy all their distressed assets at pre-specified prices, the managers’ incentive is to sell only those assets whose estimated post-crisis value is less than the offered price – to extract a subsidy from the public intervention and to minimise their immediate personal reputation loss (which is the more serious the greater the amount revealed of toxic assets). As to the fate of the bank over the longer term, they are just buying time, hoping that in the end the overall public intervention will remedy the general situation and get them out of trouble altogether. From the public interest standpoint, the risk is wasting money and not getting the result.
Similar considerations apply to the case of an insurance scheme à la Caballero (as he acknowledges), even though in this case deductible-like schemes could be devised to reduce the adverse selection problem. If government offers to recapitalise a bank, its managers have an interest in maximising the public capital injection, provided that their freedom of manoeuvre is not too strictly limited. This would go against the interest of private shareholders, who don’t want to dilute their shares, but in the present circumstances their voices are obviously very feeble. The risk for the public purse is putting too much money into banks that may be less in need than others.
If the government buys distressed assets and, at the same time, receives contingent warrants on the bank’s capital, as in Sachs’s idea, managers may want to minimise the probability of subsequent nationalisation, fearing being fired in that event, so they may not sell the whole package of troubled assets, thus jeopardising the recovery of the bank, again hoping that the systemic intervention will work and save them anyhow.
As these examples show, whatever the measure envisaged, its design is essential and must take into account, in particular, the incentives of banks’ managers, in order to make them compatible with the government’s objectives.

Disclaimer: The opinions here expressed are only the author’s and do not involve, in particular, the Bank of Italy.”

Previous Post

a DIFFERENT investment strategy?

Next Post

Credit Spreads Bump Over the 100 Mark

Related Posts

Image by CanStock
Archive

Blend Labs integrates acquisition’s mortgage automation process

August 20, 2021
Photo by CanStock
Archive

Chilean fintech looks for slice of giant money transfers market

August 5, 2021
Image by CanStock
Risk & Security

Listen: How banks can protect themselves against cybersecurity risks

August 3, 2021
Next Post

Credit Spreads Bump Over the 100 Mark

Please login to join discussion

Stay Informed with Our Newsletters

EMERGING FINTECH DIRECTORY

Emerging Fintech Directory

The Buzz Podcast

RETAIL BANKING

Huntington Bank’s new branch in Spartanburg

Huntington Bank resolves outage

May 7, 2025
bank

Barclays, Banco Santander, Lloyds plan product expansion

May 5, 2025
satisfactiin

Online banks lead FIs in customer satisfaction

May 2, 2025

SPONSORED

Just Released! 2025 Strategy Benchmark

May 1, 2025

Leverage Treasury Management to Turn Fraud Prevention Into a Strategic, Revenue-Generating Opportunity

April 1, 2025

A growth mindset in banking requires AI

March 27, 2025
  • About Us
  • Help Center
  • Contact Us
  • Privacy Terms
  • ADA Compliance
  • Advertise

 Manage Cookie Consent

Connect

twitter linkedin podcast podcast podcast
© 2025 Royal Media
No Result
View All Result
  • NEWS
    • All News
    • AI
    • Business Banking
    • Core
    • Cloud
    • Payments
    • Retail Banking
    • Risk & Security
  • DATA
  • TRANSACTIONS
  • EVENTS
    • Bank Automation Summit
  • PODCAST
  • WEBINARS
    • Upcoming Webinar
    • Webinar Library
  • SUBSCRIBE
  • Log In / Account

Welcome Back!

Login to your account below

Forgotten Password?

Retrieve your password

Please enter your username or email address to reset your password.

Log In
No Result
View All Result
  • NEWS
    • All News
    • AI
    • Business Banking
    • Core
    • Cloud
    • Payments
    • Retail Banking
    • Risk & Security
  • DATA
  • TRANSACTIONS
  • EVENTS
    • Bank Automation Summit
  • PODCAST
  • WEBINARS
    • Upcoming Webinar
    • Webinar Library
  • SUBSCRIBE
  • Log In / Account

THIS WEBSITE USES COOKIES

We use cookies on our website to give you the most relevant experience by remembering your preferences and repeat visits. By clicking “I CONSENT”, you consent to the use of ALL the cookies.

Cookie settingsI CONSENT

Review our Cookie Policies
.
Manage Cookie Consent

Privacy Overview

This website uses cookies to improve your experience while you navigate through the website. Out of these cookies, the cookies that are categorized as necessary are stored on your browser as they are essential for the working of basic functionalities of the website. We also use third-party cookies that help us analyze and understand how you use this website. These cookies will be stored in your browser only with your consent. You also have the option to opt-out of these cookies. But opting out of some of these cookies may have an effect on your browsing experience.
Necessary
Always Enabled
Necessary cookies are absolutely essential for the website to function properly. These cookies ensure basic functionalities and security features of the website, anonymously.
CookieDurationDescription
__cfruidsessionCloudflare sets this cookie to identify trusted web traffic.
__RequestVerificationTokensessionThis cookie is set by web application built in ASP.NET MVC Technologies. This is an anti-forgery cookie used for preventing cross site request forgery attacks.
_abck1 yearThis cookie is used to detect and defend when a client attempt to replay a cookie.This cookie manages the interaction with online bots and takes the appropriate actions.
34f6831605sessionGeneral purpose platform session cookie, used by sites written in JSP. Usually used to maintain an anonymous user session by the server.
a64cedc0bfsessionGeneral purpose platform session cookie, used by sites written in JSP. Usually used to maintain an anonymous user session by the server.
ak_bmsc2 hoursThis cookie is used by Akamai to optimize site security by distinguishing between humans and bots
ARRAffinitysessionARRAffinity cookie is set by Azure app service, and allows the service to choose the right instance established by a user to deliver subsequent requests made by that user.
ARRAffinitySameSitesessionThis cookie is set by Windows Azure cloud, and is used for load balancing to make sure the visitor page requests are routed to the same server in any browsing session.
AWSELBsessionAssociated with Amazon Web Services and created by Elastic Load Balancing, AWSELB cookie is used to manage sticky sessions across production servers.
bm_sz4 hoursThis cookie is set by the provider Akamai Bot Manager. This cookie is used to manage the interaction with the online bots. It also helps in fraud preventions
cf_ob_infopastThe cf_ob_info cookie is set by Cloudflare to provide information on HTTP Status Code returned by the origin web server, the Ray ID of the original failed request and the data center serving the traffic.
cf_use_obpastCloudflare sets this cookie to improve page load times and to disallow any security restrictions based on the visitor's IP address.
CONCRETE5sessionThis cookie is set by the provider Concrete5 web content management system. This is a necessary cookie used for maintaining the user session between pages.
connect.sid1 monthThis cookie is used for authentication and for secure log-in. It registers the log-in information.
cookielawinfo-checkbox-advertisement1 yearSet by the GDPR Cookie Consent plugin, this cookie is used to record the user consent for the cookies in the "Advertisement" category .
cookielawinfo-checkbox-analytics11 monthsThis cookie is set by GDPR Cookie Consent plugin. The cookie is used to store the user consent for the cookies in the category "Analytics".
cookielawinfo-checkbox-functional11 monthsThe cookie is set by GDPR cookie consent to record the user consent for the cookies in the category "Functional".
cookielawinfo-checkbox-necessary11 monthsThis cookie is set by GDPR Cookie Consent plugin. The cookies is used to store the user consent for the cookies in the category "Necessary".
cookielawinfo-checkbox-others11 monthsThis cookie is set by GDPR Cookie Consent plugin. The cookie is used to store the user consent for the cookies in the category "Other.
cookielawinfo-checkbox-performance11 monthsThis cookie is set by GDPR Cookie Consent plugin. The cookie is used to store the user consent for the cookies in the category "Performance".
cookiesession11 yearThis cookie is set by the Fortinet firewall. This cookie is used for protecting the website from abuse.
crmcsrsessionGeneral purpose platform session cookie, used by sites written in JSP. Usually used to maintain an anonymous user session by the server.
ep20130 minutesThis cookie is set by Wufoo for load balancing, site traffic and preventing site abuse.
JSESSIONIDsessionThe JSESSIONID cookie is used by New Relic to store a session identifier so that New Relic can monitor session counts for an application.
LS_CSRF_TOKENsessionCloudflare sets this cookie to track users’ activities across multiple websites. It expires once the browser is closed.
PHPSESSIDsessionThis cookie is native to PHP applications. The cookie is used to store and identify a users' unique session ID for the purpose of managing user session on the website. The cookie is a session cookies and is deleted when all the browser windows are closed.
sxa_sitesessionThis cookie is used to identify the webiste visitor's session state across page requests on server.
ts3 yearsPayPal sets this cookie to enable secure transactions through PayPal.
ts_c3 yearsPayPal sets this cookie to make safe payments through PayPal.
viewed_cookie_policy11 monthsThe cookie is set by the GDPR Cookie Consent plugin and is used to store whether or not user has consented to the use of cookies. It does not store any personal data.
wordpress_test_cookiesessionThis cookie is used to check if the cookies are enabled on the users' browser.
Functional
Functional cookies help to perform certain functionalities like sharing the content of the website on social media platforms, collect feedbacks, and other third-party features.
CookieDurationDescription
__cf_bm30 minutesThis cookie, set by Cloudflare, is used to support Cloudflare Bot Management.
_zcsr_tmpsessionZoho sets this cookie for the login function on the website.
663a60c55dsessionThis cookie is related to Zoho (Customer Service) Chatbox
bcookie2 yearsLinkedIn sets this cookie from LinkedIn share buttons and ad tags to recognize browser ID.
bscookie2 yearsLinkedIn sets this cookie to store performed actions on the website.
e188bc05fesessionThis cookie is set in relation to Zoho Campaigns
geosessionThis cookie is used for identifying the geographical location by country of the user.
iamcsrsessionZoho (Customer Support) sets this cookie and is used for tracking visitors (for performance purposes)
langsessionLinkedIn sets this cookie to remember a user's language setting.
languagesessionThis cookie is used to store the language preference of the user.
lidc1 dayLinkedIn sets the lidc cookie to facilitate data center selection.
optimizelyEndUserId1 yearOptimizely uses this cookie to store a visitor's unique identifier which is a combination of a timestamp and a random number. Different variations of web parts are shown to users that optimizes the website's user experience.
tableau_localesessionTableau uses this cookie to determine the preferred language and country-setting of the visitor - This allows the website to show content most relevant to that region and language.
UserMatchHistory1 monthLinkedIn sets this cookie for LinkedIn Ads ID syncing.
Performance
Performance cookies are used to understand and analyze the key performance indexes of the website which helps in delivering a better user experience for the visitors.
CookieDurationDescription
AWSELBCORS20 minutesThis cookie is used by Elastic Load Balancing from Amazon Web Services to effectively balance load on the servers.
Analytics
Analytical cookies are used to understand how visitors interact with the website. These cookies help provide information on metrics the number of visitors, bounce rate, traffic source, etc.
CookieDurationDescription
__gads1 year 24 daysThe __gads cookie, set by Google, is stored under DoubleClick domain and tracks the number of times users see an advert, measures the success of the campaign and calculates its revenue. This cookie can only be read from the domain they are set on and will not track any data while browsing through other sites.
_ga2 yearsThe _ga cookie, installed by Google Analytics, calculates visitor, session and campaign data and also keeps track of site usage for the site's analytics report. The cookie stores information anonymously and assigns a randomly generated number to recognize unique visitors.
_gcl_au3 monthsProvided by Google Tag Manager to experiment advertisement efficiency of websites using their services.
_gid1 dayInstalled by Google Analytics, _gid cookie stores information on how visitors use a website, while also creating an analytics report of the website's performance. Some of the data that are collected include the number of visitors, their source, and the pages they visit anonymously.
ajs_anonymous_idneverThis cookie is set by Segment to count the number of people who visit a certain site by tracking if they have visited before.
ajs_group_idneverThis cookie is set by Segment to track visitor usage and events within the website.
ajs_user_idneverThis cookie is set by Segment to help track visitor usage, events, target marketing, and also measure application performance and stability.
browser_id5 yearsThis cookie is used for identifying the visitor browser on re-visit to the website.
CONSENT2 yearsYouTube sets this cookie via embedded youtube-videos and registers anonymous statistical data.
sid1 yearThe sid cookie contains digitally signed and encrypted records of a user’s Google account ID and most recent sign-in time.
uid1 yearThis is a Google UserID cookie that tracks users across various website segments.
vuid2 yearsVimeo installs this cookie to collect tracking information by setting a unique ID to embed videos to the website.
WMF-Last-Access1 month 21 hours 5 minutesThis cookie is used to calculate unique devices accessing the website.
Advertisement
Advertisement cookies are used to provide visitors with relevant ads and marketing campaigns. These cookies track visitors across websites and collect information to provide customized ads.
CookieDurationDescription
_dc_gtm_UA-1038974-41 minuteUsed to help identify the visitors by either age, gender, or interests by DoubleClick - Google Tag Manager.
_fbp3 monthsThis cookie is set by Facebook to display advertisements when either on Facebook or on a digital platform powered by Facebook advertising, after visiting the website.
_pxhdpastUsed by Zoominfo to enhance customer data.
fr3 monthsFacebook sets this cookie to show relevant advertisements to users by tracking user behaviour across the web, on sites that have Facebook pixel or Facebook social plugin.
IDE1 year 24 daysGoogle DoubleClick IDE cookies are used to store information about how the user uses the website to present them with relevant ads and according to the user profile.
test_cookie15 minutesThe test_cookie is set by doubleclick.net and is used to determine if the user's browser supports cookies.
VISITOR_INFO1_LIVE5 months 27 daysA cookie set by YouTube to measure bandwidth that determines whether the user gets the new or old player interface.
YSCsessionYSC cookie is set by Youtube and is used to track the views of embedded videos on Youtube pages.
yt-remote-connected-devicesneverYouTube sets this cookie to store the video preferences of the user using embedded YouTube video.
yt-remote-device-idneverYouTube sets this cookie to store the video preferences of the user using embedded YouTube video.
yt.innertube::nextIdneverThis cookie, set by YouTube, registers a unique ID to store data on what videos from YouTube the user has seen.
yt.innertube::requestsneverThis cookie, set by YouTube, registers a unique ID to store data on what videos from YouTube the user has seen.
Others
Other uncategorized cookies are those that are being analyzed and have not been classified into a category as yet.
CookieDurationDescription
049fc2ef5beb27056b07d9e4c4d13fd3sessionNo description
akaalb_http_misc_subssessionNo description
AnalyticsSyncHistory1 monthNo description
BIGipServermsocu-web-2-rr.webfarm.ms.com.10882sessionNo description
bm_misessionNo description available.
CX_4061522881 yearNo description
DCID20 minutesNo description
debugneverNo description available.
DrupalVisitorMobilesessionNo description available.
ep2033 monthsNo description available.
frbatlanta#langsessionNo description
geo_info1 yearNo description available.
GoogleAdServingTestsessionNo description
li_gc2 yearsNo description
loglevelneverNo description available.
loom_anon_commentsessionNo description available.
loom_referral_videosessionNo description
mkjs_group_idneverNo description available.
mkjs_user_idneverNo description available.
MorganStanley.ClientServ.Common.IPZipAccess.IPZipCookie.DEFAULT_COOKIE_NAMEpastNo description
NSC_us_nbsl-83+63+21+25-91sessionNo description
nyt-a1 yearThis cookie is set by the provider New York Times. This cookie is used for saving the user preferences. It is used in context with video and audio content.
nyt-gdpr6 hoursNo description available.
nyt-purr1 yearNo description available.
OCC_Encrypted_CookiesessionNo description
polleverywhere_session_id14 daysNo description
ppnet_2020sessionNo description available.
ppnet_2777sessionNo description available.
reuters-geosessionNo description
shell#langsessionNo description
smcx_0_last_shown_atsessionNo description available.
tableau_public_negotiated_localesessionNo description available.
vary1 monthNo description
www#langsessionNo description
X-Vive-CountrysessionNo description
xn_uuid1 monthNo description
Save & Accept
Powered by CookieYes Logo